Author:
(1) David Staines.
4 Calvo Framework and 4.1 Household’s Problem
4.3 Household Equilibrium Conditions
4.5 Nominal Equilibrium Conditions
4.6 Real Equilibrium Conditions and 4.7 Shocks
5.2 Persistence and Policy Puzzles
6 Stochastic Equilibrium and 6.1 Ergodic Theory and Random Dynamical Systems
7 General Linearized Phillips Curve
8 Existence Results and 8.1 Main Results
9.2 Algebraic Aspects (I) Singularities and Covers
9.3 Algebraic Aspects (II) Homology
9.4 Algebraic Aspects (III) Schemes
9.5 Wider Economic Interpretations
10 Econometric and Theoretical Implications and 10.1 Identification and Trade-offs
10.4 Microeconomic Interpretation
Appendices
A Proof of Theorem 2 and A.1 Proof of Part (i)
B Proofs from Section 4 and B.1 Individual Product Demand (4.2)
B.2 Flexible Price Equilibrium and ZINSS (4.4)
B.4 Cost Minimization (4.6) and (10.4)
C Proofs from Section 5, and C.1 Puzzles, Policy and Persistence
D Stochastic Equilibrium and D.1 Non-Stochastic Equilibrium
D.2 Profits and Long-Run Growth
E Slopes and Eigenvalues and E.1 Slope Coefficients
E.4 Rouche’s Theorem Conditions
F Abstract Algebra and F.1 Homology Groups
F.4 Marginal Costs and Inflation
G Further Keynesian Models and G.1 Taylor Pricing
G.3 Unconventional Policy Settings
H Empirical Robustness and H.1 Parameter Selection
I Additional Evidence and I.1 Other Structural Parameters
I.3 Trend Inflation Volatility
This section focuses on the most basic economic theory embedded in the coefficients of the Phillips curve. It sketches out the fundamental policy and econometric implications of this theory. I chart a new course for macroeconomic policy analysis and suggest new avenues for econometric research.
The first task of this section is to prove that price rigidity implies first order trade-offs between stabilization objectives. The second is to show that this naturally resolves econometric problems with identification. These conditions constitute natural well-posedness conditions for dynamic stochastic models.
Here, I establish the existence of trade-offs in monetary policy setting, previously thought not to exist in such benchmark setting. In particular, it overturns Proposition 6 for the Calvo model. I begin with an interesting preliminary result of interest throughout this subsection.
The simple proof occupies Appendix G.3.1. It is instructive to discuss further this special case. The first viewpoint is topological, it complements the bifurcation analysis of Section 9. The second focus on theoretical interpretations.
Remark 28. This special case amounts to the Central Bank engineering financial frictions, which move the economy back to an ad hoc demand curve.
This was traditionally how Keynesian models were constructed. Microfounded demand curves were seen as a restrictive afterthought. I have overturned this view. They are a necessary stabilizing force. This symbiosis of Keynesian and Classical mechanisms is a subtle yet significant feature of modern Keynesian economics.
Nevertheless, the practical significance is limited. The policy would be inconsistent with central banks mandate to develop and stabilize financial markets.[91]
Theorem 8. (No Divine Coincidence) Under Calvo pricing, even if the government is able to correct static market failures, there will always arise a first order welfare loss from business cycle fluctuations.
Remark 29. This trade-off confirms the constraint interpretation of the boundary surface, prevalent in the last section.
Remark 30. This morphs into a general stabilization trade-off away from ZINSS. This is because successfully stabilizing the economy to first order, around any stochastic equilibrium, would move the economy back to the neighborhood of the non-stochastic equilibrium, since the mixing property would ensure second order terms vanished.
The problem is there are two cost-push shocks in the Phillips curve and only one policy instrument. This is the simplest possible stabilization trade-off. Although a priority, it lies beyond the scope of this paper to analyze the policy prescriptions. It also some mathematical significance.
Remark 31. The demise of Divine Coincidence demonstrates that the cost of economic fluctuations has a non-degenerate Lipschitz bound as a function of the shock size. This is a basic regularity property of the optimal policy problem.
Here I prove identification and persistence, stemming from structural shocks, without real rigidity, in opposition to Propositions 8 and 9.
Remark 32. This no persistence result breaks down in the large noise limit because of price dispersion but might arise if price dispersion were ignored.
The no persistence policy rule is counter-intuitive. Central banks seek to raise the profile of interest rates in response to increases in inflation. However, further analysis of the policy rule in Appendix G.3 is unable to rule it out. This means there is no direct counter to Proposition 8. Elsewhere in the text, I persist with non-negative reaction coefficients.
Remark 33. Persistence is necessary and sufficient for identification of the structural model (without ad hoc shocks). This can be seen from the solution in Appendix E.2, which theoretically implies an infinite number of over-identifying conditions through construction of a suitable auto-regression.
The (over)identification of structural parameters follows swiftly apart from θ, which will be dealt with in a subsequent paper. It is surely a step forward to no longer rely on unexplained and poorly motivated shocks for identification, particularly when they are not compatible with rational expectations (Proposition 7).
This pathology with persistence and the surprising non-existence results point towards optimal monetary policy. Optimal monetary policy should yield stronger regularity of solution, including the prospect of unconditional existence in many cases. It is likely to deliver clearer empirical predictions and may even simplify the solution or improve its fit. It should be a natural next step for central bank economists to include their own optimizing efforts in the regular process of monetary policy modelling.
This paper is available on arxiv under CC 4.0 license.
[91] Moreover, this is not how one would model credit constraints; even if some people were shut out of the financial system. There would be capitalists who owned the firms’ and if they were credit constrained, they would choose to close down their business. Hence we should always expect there to be some unconstrained agents. A genuine heterogeneous agent model is considerably outside the scope of the paper.