paint-brush
Why Inflation and Price Variations Matter for Economic Stabilityby@keynesian

Why Inflation and Price Variations Matter for Economic Stability

by Keynesian TechnologyDecember 6th, 2024
Read on Terminal Reader
Read this story w/o Javascript
tldt arrow

Too Long; Didn't Read

Nominal rigidity creates price dispersion, impacting utility and inflation dynamics. This leads to real distortions in equilibrium, with monetary policy analysis addressing inertia concerns.
featured image - Why Inflation and Price Variations Matter for Economic Stability
Keynesian Technology HackerNoon profile picture

Abstract

1 Introduction

2 Mathematical Arguments

3 Outline and Preview

4 Calvo Framework and 4.1 Household’s Problem

4.2 Preferences

4.3 Household Equilibrium Conditions

4.4 Price-Setting Problem

4.5 Nominal Equilibrium Conditions

4.6 Real Equilibrium Conditions and 4.7 Shocks

4.8 Recursive Equilibrium

5 Existing Solutions

5.1 Singular Phillips Curve

5.2 Persistence and Policy Puzzles

5.3 Two Comparison Models

5.4 Lucas Critique

6 Stochastic Equilibrium and 6.1 Ergodic Theory and Random Dynamical Systems

6.2 Equilibrium Construction

6.3 Literature Comparison

6.4 Equilibrium Analysis

7 General Linearized Phillips Curve

7.1 Slope Coefficients

7.2 Error Coefficients

8 Existence Results and 8.1 Main Results

8.2 Key Proofs

8.3 Discussion

9 Bifurcation Analysis

9.1 Analytic Aspects

9.2 Algebraic Aspects (I) Singularities and Covers

9.3 Algebraic Aspects (II) Homology

9.4 Algebraic Aspects (III) Schemes

9.5 Wider Economic Interpretations

10 Econometric and Theoretical Implications and 10.1 Identification and Trade-offs

10.2 Econometric Duality

10.3 Coefficient Properties

10.4 Microeconomic Interpretation

11 Policy Rule

12 Conclusions and References


Appendices

A Proof of Theorem 2 and A.1 Proof of Part (i)

A.2 Behaviour of ∆

A.3 Proof Part (iii)

B Proofs from Section 4 and B.1 Individual Product Demand (4.2)

B.2 Flexible Price Equilibrium and ZINSS (4.4)

B.3 Price Dispersion (4.5)

B.4 Cost Minimization (4.6) and (10.4)

B.5 Consolidation (4.8)

C Proofs from Section 5, and C.1 Puzzles, Policy and Persistence

C.2 Extending No Persistence

D Stochastic Equilibrium and D.1 Non-Stochastic Equilibrium

D.2 Profits and Long-Run Growth

E Slopes and Eigenvalues and E.1 Slope Coefficients

E.2 Linearized DSGE Solution

E.3 Eigenvalue Conditions

E.4 Rouche’s Theorem Conditions

F Abstract Algebra and F.1 Homology Groups

F.2 Basic Categories

F.3 De Rham Cohomology

F.4 Marginal Costs and Inflation

G Further Keynesian Models and G.1 Taylor Pricing

G.2 Calvo Wage Phillips Curve

G.3 Unconventional Policy Settings

H Empirical Robustness and H.1 Parameter Selection

H.2 Phillips Curve

I Additional Evidence and I.1 Other Structural Parameters

I.2 Lucas Critique

I.3 Trend Inflation Volatility

4.5 Nominal Equilibrium Conditions

Nominal rigidity generates real distortions through the dispersion term. The demand aggregator



represents price dispersion since



Proposition 3.is second order when approximated from ZINSS.


The first result is a global property of price dispersion, which will be called upon when analyzing the boundary conditions in the fixed-point theorem. The second is a local condition that justifies the √ ε limiting construction. Neither result is novel so proofs are relegated to Appendix B.3. The intuition is that consumers prefer variety and it is therefore costly to substitute between high and low price goods. Therefore they cannot achieve the same utility when prices are dispersed which will always arise when prices are rigid and inflation variable. Here with Calvo pricing, ∆ evolves according to the following relationship:



Using Proposition 1, I can solve for the reset price to give a recursion in inflation



Finally, there is the monetary policy rule.



When selecting such a simple rule, my key concerns were tractability and comparability with previous work. In the next part, I confirm that including lags or leads would not be justified by welfare concerns in a purely forward-looking model. This fits with my ultimate goal of justifying inertial policy from an optimal policy standpoint. My policy analysis should prove immune to timing issues and information available to the Central Bank. This is because the boundary case of inactivity is common to all possible policy rules, whilst in a persistent stochastic setting even the expectations of future variables would induce inertia.[26]


26Taylor’s actual proposal was somewhat closer to my analysis. His rule used an inflation measure averaged over the previous four quarters. Although, his motivation was different, he envisaged that the lagged inflation rate would serve as a proxy for expected inflation. In the same conference (Henderson and McKibbin [1993]) came up with a very similar formulation.


Author:

(1) David Staines.


This paper is available on arxiv under CC 4.0 license.