paint-brush
Hyperinflation Model Successfully Explains Rapid Inflation Escalationโ€‚by@hyperinflation
New Story

Hyperinflation Model Successfully Explains Rapid Inflation Escalation

by Hyper InflationJanuary 2nd, 2025
Read on Terminal Reader
Read this story w/o Javascript
tldt arrow

Too Long; Didn't Read

How changes in the money supply, economic growth, and savings levels affect inflation and when and why inflation might escalate into hyperinflation.
featured image - Hyperinflation Model Successfully Explains Rapid Inflation Escalation
Hyper Inflation HackerNoon profile picture

Author:

(1) Laurence Francis Lacey, Lacey Solutions Ltd, Skerries, County Dublin, Ireland.

Editor's Note: This is Part 6 of 7 of a study on how changes in the money supply, economic growth, and savings levels affect inflation. Read the rest below.

4. Discussion

The consumer price inflation model described is intended to investigate the consumer price index (CPI), over a period of years and not over a period of months, in order to investigate the longer-term relationships involved. In contrast, the hyperinflation model described is intended to investigate the increase in nominal prices, over a period of months, because of the accelerating nature of the decline in the purchasing power of the fiat currency being studied. Unlike in the case of hyperinflation, under โ€œordinaryโ€ circumstances, the growth in price inflation has a velocity, but the acceleration can be ignored because it is approximately constant, i.e., price inflation increases at an approximate constant rate with time.


The hypothesis that the annual rate of growth in the US CPI is a function of the annual growth in the US broad money supply minus the annual growth in US real GDP minus the annual growth in US savings, over the time period 2001 to 2019, has been shown to be the case. However, an exact relationship required the use of a non-zero residual term, RES(t):


๐‘ฃ๐ถ๐‘ƒ๐ผ(๐‘ก) = ๐‘ฃ๐ต๐‘€๐‘†(๐‘ก) โˆ’ ๐‘ฃ๐บ๐ท๐‘ƒ(๐‘ก) โˆ’ ๐‘ฃ๐‘†๐ด๐‘‰(๐‘ก) โˆ’ ๐‘…๐ธ๐‘†(๐‘ก)


This may be the case for a couple of reasons:


(1) The measure of savings used was the estimated average annual American household savings [11]. While, this might be expected to be technically challenging to calculate accurately, it only pertains to households. It might be expected that in addition to average annual American household savings, there should also exist annual American non-household savings. Therefore, a limitation of this paper is that American household savings were used as a measure of overall savings in the US economy.


(2) There may be an additional factor that needed to be included in the model, other than savings.


Savings were included in the model because savings can be used, if required / desired to purchase goods and/or services, or not, as the case might be, and as a result might be expected to influence the CPI. An alternative approach might be to use another broad measure of the money supply that excludes savings.


The model includes the terms, BMS and GDP. So also does the concept of the โ€œvelocity of moneyโ€ [15], in which:


"๐‘ฃ๐‘’๐‘™๐‘œ๐‘๐‘–๐‘ก๐‘ฆ ๐‘œ๐‘“ ๐‘š๐‘œ๐‘›๐‘’๐‘ฆ" = ๐บ๐ท๐‘ƒ/๐‘€๐‘œ๐‘›๐‘’๐‘ฆ ๐‘†๐‘ข๐‘๐‘๐‘™๐‘ฆ


This equation can be rearranged as follow:



However, for the concept of the โ€œvelocity of moneyโ€ to be relevant to this paper, it would need to be expressed in terms of its constant rate of change with time, as follows:



Should the CPI model be valid (subject to the caveat discussed above in relation to savings) such that:


๐‘ฃ๐ถ๐‘ƒ๐ผ(๐‘ก) = ๐‘ฃ๐ต๐‘€๐‘†(๐‘ก) โˆ’ ๐‘ฃ๐บ๐ท๐‘ƒ(๐‘ก) โˆ’ ๐‘ฃ๐‘†๐ด๐‘‰(๐‘ก)


this would predict a few different economic scenarios:


(1) When there is no (or very little) growth in GDP or savings (โ€œstagflation scenarioโ€):


๐‘ฃ๐ถ๐‘ƒ๐ผ(๐‘ก) = ๐‘ฃ๐ต๐‘€๐‘†(๐‘ก)


(2) When the growth in savings is sufficiently high, the growth in CPI could turn negative (โ€œdeflation scenarioโ€).


(3) When there is negative growth in GDP (โ€œrecession scenarioโ€), the growth in CPI could be greater than the growth in BMS, should there be no โ€œrebalancingโ€ change in the growth of BMS.


A mathematical statistical formulation of a hyperinflationary process has been provided and used to quantify the period of hyperinflation in the Weimar Republic from July 1922 until the end of November 1923. Why did this hyperinflationary happen and why was it allowed to occur by the Government and central bankers of the Weimar Republic?


As outlined in [14], following World War 1 and the Treaty of Versailles (which came into effect on January 10, 1920), the strategy that Germany used to pay war reparations was the mass printing of bank notes to buy foreign currency, which was then used to pay reparations, but which also caused inflation of the paper mark. After Germany failed to pay France an instalment of reparations on time in late 1922, French and Belgian troops occupied the Ruhr valley, Germany's main industrial region, in January 1923. The German government's response was to order a policy of passive resistance in the Ruhr, akin to a general strike, to protest the occupation, while providing financial assistance to the striking workers by printing more and more banknotes, with the result that the paper mark became increasing worthless throughout 1923.


The mathematical statistical formulation of a hyperinflationary process could be extended beyond two sequential exponential expansions to include any arbitrary number (n) of sequential exponential expansions. However, while this may have theoretical interest, it is not a phenomenon that has yet occurred in real-world economics, to the knowledge of the author.


This paper is available on arxiv under CC BY-NC-ND 4.0 DEED license.