paint-brush
Exploring the Relationship Between Flexible Price Equilibrium and ZINSS in Economic Modelsby@keynesian
New Story

Exploring the Relationship Between Flexible Price Equilibrium and ZINSS in Economic Models

by Keynesian TechnologyDecember 9th, 2024
Read on Terminal Reader
Read this story w/o Javascript
tldt arrow

Too Long; Didn't Read

This subsection explains the relationship between optimal reset prices and flexible price equilibrium, showing their coincidence under zero inflation, and discusses the role of nominal rigidity in economic models.
featured image - Exploring the Relationship Between Flexible Price Equilibrium and ZINSS in Economic Models
Keynesian Technology HackerNoon profile picture

Author:

(1) David Staines.

Abstract

1 Introduction

2 Mathematical Arguments

3 Outline and Preview

4 Calvo Framework and 4.1 Household’s Problem

4.2 Preferences

4.3 Household Equilibrium Conditions

4.4 Price-Setting Problem

4.5 Nominal Equilibrium Conditions

4.6 Real Equilibrium Conditions and 4.7 Shocks

4.8 Recursive Equilibrium

5 Existing Solutions

5.1 Singular Phillips Curve

5.2 Persistence and Policy Puzzles

5.3 Two Comparison Models

5.4 Lucas Critique

6 Stochastic Equilibrium and 6.1 Ergodic Theory and Random Dynamical Systems

6.2 Equilibrium Construction

6.3 Literature Comparison

6.4 Equilibrium Analysis

7 General Linearized Phillips Curve

7.1 Slope Coefficients

7.2 Error Coefficients

8 Existence Results and 8.1 Main Results

8.2 Key Proofs

8.3 Discussion

9 Bifurcation Analysis

9.1 Analytic Aspects

9.2 Algebraic Aspects (I) Singularities and Covers

9.3 Algebraic Aspects (II) Homology

9.4 Algebraic Aspects (III) Schemes

9.5 Wider Economic Interpretations

10 Econometric and Theoretical Implications and 10.1 Identification and Trade-offs

10.2 Econometric Duality

10.3 Coefficient Properties

10.4 Microeconomic Interpretation

11 Policy Rule

12 Conclusions and References


Appendices

A Proof of Theorem 2 and A.1 Proof of Part (i)

A.2 Behaviour of ∆

A.3 Proof Part (iii)

B Proofs from Section 4 and B.1 Individual Product Demand (4.2)

B.2 Flexible Price Equilibrium and ZINSS (4.4)

B.3 Price Dispersion (4.5)

B.4 Cost Minimization (4.6) and (10.4)

B.5 Consolidation (4.8)

C Proofs from Section 5, and C.1 Puzzles, Policy and Persistence

C.2 Extending No Persistence

D Stochastic Equilibrium and D.1 Non-Stochastic Equilibrium

D.2 Profits and Long-Run Growth

E Slopes and Eigenvalues and E.1 Slope Coefficients

E.2 Linearized DSGE Solution

E.3 Eigenvalue Conditions

E.4 Rouche’s Theorem Conditions

F Abstract Algebra and F.1 Homology Groups

F.2 Basic Categories

F.3 De Rham Cohomology

F.4 Marginal Costs and Inflation

G Further Keynesian Models and G.1 Taylor Pricing

G.2 Calvo Wage Phillips Curve

G.3 Unconventional Policy Settings

H Empirical Robustness and H.1 Parameter Selection

H.2 Phillips Curve

I Additional Evidence and I.1 Other Structural Parameters

I.2 Lucas Critique

I.3 Trend Inflation Volatility

B.2 Flexible Price Equilibrium and ZINSS (4.4)

This subsection clarifies remarks concerning the relationship between the optimal reset price and the flexible price equilibrium, including their coincidence when there is zero inflation. To achieve this I introduce a little mathematical machinery, that I understand to be original. Under monopolistic competition, I find that the optimal price is a mark-up m = 1/(θ − 1) over marginal costs, so in real terms



It is worth briefly motivating this definition. Continuity and increasing requirements support the idea of the mean as an average and rule out alternative measures of location, such as median and mode.[106] The function space assumption allows us to include expectations of future variables, as part of our average ensemble. It is this averaging property that underpins ergodicity and mixing in the model.



Proof. Weak measurability comes from the structure of the optimization problem. Monotonicity and continuity follow from the following implicit function argument, where the left-hand side is (27), combined with (199) and the gross inflation definition (23) on the right-hand side



Hence



Corollary 3. ZINSS is equivalent to a flexible price equilibrium.



Therefore uniquely at ZINSS the reset price constraint is not binding. This confirms the breakdown of nominal rigidity as the root cause of the bifurcation. The other weighted measures feature expectations of non-linear terms and are therefore not amenable to our definition.


Remark 36. These results carry over easily to alternative settings with finite price lives. This includes Taylor pricing and models where the price spell is truncated, such as Wolman [1999] and Dixon and Le Bihan [2012].


The final result justifies a comment in Footnote 25 in Section 4.4. It explains the distinction between the reset price and the flexible price. Moreover, it presages the idea of a limiting fringe of flexible price firms, used in Section 9.5 to make distinctions between real and nominal rigidity.


Proposition 28. The magnitude of the change in the reset price weakly exceeds the change in the price of a firm that always had flexible prices, with equality only when neither price changes.


Proof. Since price re-setters are randomly assigned here, by a standard law of large numbers argument, the reset price inflation is given by



A flexible price firm will always set its price equal to the general price level



(202) corresponds to Proposition 1, the economic idea that the relative price of the re-setter is increasing in inflation. Intuitively, with rigid prices to generate inflation or deflation, re-setters have to adjust more aggressively than in the flexible price world, in order to make up for the portion of the price level that does not change. This is why we cannot naively compare observed price changes with a classical benchmark to obtain the spillover from rigid prices to flexible prices.


This paper is available on arxiv under CC 4.0 license.


[105] A reflexive space has the property that the set of possible ensemble averages and the set of possible realizations coincide.


[106] Consult Bullen [2003] for a review of mean concepts and their inequalities.