paint-brush
Theorems on Error Variance in the Black-Scholes Frameworkโ€‚by@hedging

Theorems on Error Variance in the Black-Scholes Framework

by Economic Hedging TechnologyOctober 23rd, 2024
Read on Terminal Reader
tldt arrow

Too Long; Didn't Read

This section outlines three key theorems that examine hedge error variance in delta hedging within the Black-Scholes framework. Theorems demonstrate that selecting the right hedge portfolio can reduce hedge errors by focusing on systematic risk exposures. The final theorem establishes that, with sufficient diversification, a riskless hedging strategy can be achieved, effectively eliminating systematic risk and idiosyncratic risk.
featured image - Theorems on Error Variance in the Black-Scholes Framework
Economic Hedging Technology HackerNoon profile picture

Abstract and 1. Introduction

1.1 Option Pricing

1.2 Asymptotic Notation (Big O)

1.3 Finite Difference

1.4 The Black-Schole Model

1.5 Monte Carlo Simulation and Variance Reduction Techniques

1.6 Our Contribution

  1. Literature Review
  2. Methodology

3.1 Model Assumption

3.2 Theorems and Model Discussion

  1. Result Analysis
  2. Conclusion and References

3.2 THEOREMS AND MODEL DISCUSSION

The three steps we take are outlined in Theorems 1 through 3. We begin by deriving an equation for the hedge error variance in the case when each call position in the portfolio has a standard delta hedge applied to it [22]. Following that, To protect against changes in the value of the option portfolio, we create an analogous formula for the scenario in which an arbitrary portfolio in the underlying values is retained [23]. As a result, we are able to show how selecting the right hedge portfolio helps lower hedge error variances. We last provide our major theoretical finding, which demonstrates that by focusing only on the linear and higher order exposures to the systematic risk factor [24], it becomes possible to design a perfect static hedge portfolio in finite time, provided that the portfolio size grows infinitely [25].



Hedge error is defined by โˆ†๐ป as



The hedge portfolio is the total of the hedge portfolios for each individual position when using the hedging approach described above [26]. We create a power series by expanding the hedge mistake (14) [27]. Regarding the duration of the hedging period โˆ†๐‘ก, See Leland (1985) as well as Mello and Neuhaus (1998). The predicted hedging error and its variation under the current conventional delta hedging method are as follows [28].


Theorem 1: The hedging error โˆ†๐ป in (14), which is obtained through delta hedging of the individual option holdings, satisfies



Essentially, for N = 1, we obtain the square of the option's gamma, which is the well-known calculation for the hedge error variance [3].


Figure 2: Optionโ€™s Gamma


This variance's explicit representation clearly indicates that the option portfolio's return is no longer reproduced riskfree in a defined amount of time using the Black-Scholes hedging strategy. Thus, it appears that the option portfolio does not have a unique preference free pricing.



With this unconventional approach to hedging, we get the following outcome for the hedge error variance.




Figure 3: Optionโ€™s Delta




There is a trade-off between insuring all idiosyncratic risk (in the limit ๐‘›โˆ†๐‘ก โ†’ 0 , the traditional Black-Scholes technique) and hedging market risk exclusively (in the limit ๐‘›โˆ†๐‘ก โ†’โˆž) for finite portfolio size ๐‘› and finite revision time โˆ†๐‘ก. Clearly, with bigger portfolio sizes and revision intervals, there are more departures from the traditional hedging technique in terms of hedge ratios and variance reduction. Now that we have established the general conclusion, we may argue that it is better to hedge higher order systematic risk rather than linear idiosyncratic risk in big option portfolios. The subsequent theorem does this.



One can demonstrate a similar outcome if idiosyncratic risk is valued [3]. In that scenario, the quantity of securities required to build the hedging portfolio grows quadratically with ๐‘Ž. Furthermore, there are now prospects for arbitrage since the projected return of this hedging approach need not be zero. This is to be expected because arbitrage is possible in a market structure that doesn't even have options [24].


Figure 4: Hedge error with a lesser number of time steps


Theorem 3's result shows that if the ๐œ‘๐‘– s are different, we can create a riskless hedging strategy for finite time โˆ†๐‘ก in the limit ๐‘› โ†’โˆž. Stated otherwise, the risk incurred by switching to a discrete time setup entirely disappears: by selecting the suitable non-standard hedging approach, the systematic risk component can be eliminated to any arbitrary order of โˆ†๐‘ก. Diversification causes the idiosyncratic risk component to vanish at the same time. The hedge portfolio is selected so that, up to a high enough order in โˆ†t, its expectation conditional on the systematic risk component corresponds with its unconditional expectation. This is the key to the demonstration. By matching the higher order properties of the systematic risk exposure, this may be proven. The portfolio loadings ๐œ“ ๐‘– must be subject to a series of restrictions in order to meet the two sorts of expectations. In the ๐œ“ ๐‘– s, each of these restrictions is linear. The coefficients of these constraints entail powers of the systematic volatility ๐œ‘๐‘– and higher order derivatives of the Black-Scholes price (to capture the proper curvature). The number of securities, ๐‘› โ‰ฅ ๐‘Ž, must be sufficiently large in order for this set of constraints to have a solution. Secondly, the limitations system must not be unique. Requiring that at least ๐‘Ž of the ๐œ‘๐‘– s be different and not equal to zero ensures the latter.


In the current discrete time framework, one can question if the Black-Scholes pricing remain accurate, given the stark differences between the behavior of the conventional and portfolio hedging approaches. They are, according to the next corollary.


Corollary 1 (the price is right): If only market risk is priced and the number of securities diverges (๐‘› โ†’โˆž), and if the ๐œ‘๐‘– s are different such that we can set the approximation order n arbitrarily high (๐‘Ž โ†’โˆž), then the only arbitrage-free price of the options is equal to their Black-Scholes price, except for a set of measure zero.


According to Corollary 1, arbitrage opportunities are those in which there is an almost certain chance of earning a return greater than the risk-free rate [3]. The hedge portfolio is priced the same as Black-Scholes by construction. This suggests that the total of the Black-Scholes prices and the options prices are equal, based on the outcome of Theorem 3. However, Theorem 3 also holds for all call option subseries and their underlying values, meaning that the set of options with prices that deviate from the Black-Scholes price has measured zero.


Authors:

(1) Agni Rakshit, Department of Mathematics, National Institute of Technology, Durgapur, Durgapur, India ([email protected]);

(2) Gautam Bandyopadhyay, Department of Management Studies, National Institute of Technology, Durgapur, Durgapur, India ([email protected]);

(3) Tanujit Chakraborty, Department of Science and Engineering & Sorbonne Center for AI, Sorbonne University, Abu Dhabi, United Arab Emirates ([email protected]).


This paper is available on arxiv under CC by 4.0 Deed (Attribution 4.0 International) license.